Assessing the Land Use Changes and Greenhouse Gas Emissions of Biofuels: Elucidating the Crop Yield Effects

Alexandre Gohin

Abstract

Available estimates of the land use changes and greenhouse gas emissions of biofuels differ significantly across economic models. This paper focuses on the impacts of price-induced yield assumptions on U.S. corn ethanol results. These assumptions have dramatic impacts within the FAPRI modeling framework, but limited ones within the GTAP-BIO model. I show that these sensitivity to yield assumption results are not comparable because the ex ante land and production elasticities assumed in these two models are not comparable. The analysis reveals that the current focus solely on the value of the price-induced yield elasticity can be misleading. (JEL Q11, Q28)

I. The Issue

Both the United States and the European Union have implemented biofuel policies in the last decade with the aims of supporting farm incomes, reducing dependency on fossil fuels, and mitigating global warming effects. However, concerning the last objective, biofuels may underperform if they involve significant land use changes leading to additional greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions. Since observed land use changes result from many factors, many economic models have been devised to sort out the specific contribution of biofuels in these observed or projected changes. These models can be partial equilibrium (PE), focusing on the agricultural and biofuel markets, or general equilibrium (GE), capturing all sectors and markets. Not surprisingly, the numerous studies and underlying economic models lead to very different figures (see, e.g., the survey by Edwards, Mulligan, and Marelli 2010). Moreover, these studies generally acknowledge the great uncertainties surrounding their central estimates due to uncertain values of certain model parameters (see, e.g., Elobeid et al. 2012, FAPRI PE model; Golub and Hertel 2012, GTAP-BIO GE model; Laborde and Valin 2012, MIRAGE-BioF GE model).

By definition, these PE and GE economic models assume certain behavioral specifications and parameter values that drive their results. One widely debated assumption concerns the crop yield responses to commodity prices. It is common sense to assume that a greater responsiveness of crop yields decreases land use requirements due to biofuel expansion. Early assessments of biofuels (e.g., Searchinger et al. 2008) assumed no crop yield effects. Recent assessments show that the introduction of crop yield responses decreases land use changes and then increases the GHG savings of biofuels (see, e.g., Broch, Hoekman, and Unnasch 2013). Even Golub and Hertel (2012), with the GTAP-BIO framework, and Dumortier et al. (2011), with the FAPRI framework, find that the crop yield responses are the most critical parameters in their assessments.

More surprisingly, the impact of crop yield responses on land use changes and GHG results greatly depends on the economic framework. In this paper, my analysis focuses on U.S. corn-based ethanol, which is now the major biofuel consumed in the world. I concentrate on two well-documented economic models, the FAPRI and the GTAP-BIO, that were influential in recent U.S. policy decisions. On the one hand, Dumortier et al. (2011), using the FAPRI model, find that if the output price elasticity of major crop yields increases from 0 to approximately 0.15 (depending on country and crop), then the carbon emission from the land use changes decreases from 107 to 14 gCO2eq/MJ (hence, an 87% decrease). By contrast, the California Air Resources Board (CARB 2009) reports with the GTAP-BIO model that when the output price elasticity of crop yields increases from 0.2 to 0.4, the carbon emission from the land use changes decreases from 44 to 34 gCO2eq/MJ (hence, a 23% decrease).1 In other words, for similar absolute increases in the crop yield responses, the ultimate impacts on carbon emission are quite different. The policy implications of these results are completely different. When higher crop yield responses are taken into account, biofuel policies may deliver true GHG savings according to the FAPRI results; however, they are more likely to remain GHG inefficient according to the GTAP-BIO results.

The main purpose of this paper is to elucidate the impact of crop yield responses on the land use changes and net GHG emissions of biofuels. My analysis applies to the often-studied U.S. production of ethanol from corn. I focus on the GTAP-BIO model for two reasons. One first obvious reason is the public availability of this model so that everyone can test it (the following analysis starts from the version available on the CARB website). The second reason is that the GE approach used in the GTAP-BIO model offers an explicit representation of agricultural production technologies and of farmer behaviors. More precisely, this GTAP-BIO model determines the levels of variable inputs (such as chemical inputs, energy products) and primary factors (such as land, capital) that are effectively used by farmers. These inputs and factors are optimally chosen by farmers who maximize their profits subject to technical constraints (specified by standard constant elasticity of substitution [CES] functions). Crop yields are then simply computed at the end of the simulations by the ratio of optimal production to optimal land uses. By contrast, the FAPRI PE framework adopts a reduced form specification without an explicit modeling of the different inputs used for farming and technological constraints.

The contributions of this paper are twofold. First, it reveals analytically that the calibrated crop yield responses in the GTAP-BIO framework imply that the ex ante yield effects represent approximately 10% of the production effects. By contrast, the available information from the FAPRI framework suggests that these ex ante yield effects are close to 40% of the production effects. In other words, even if the ex ante yield elasticities are similar across the two frameworks, the ex ante production elasticities (and land elasticities) are very different. Hence, for a similar increase in agricultural production, the ex ante land use changes remain extensive in the GTAP-BIO framework (at approximately 90%), while they are significantly reduced in the FAPRI framework (at 40%).

Second, it reports the main results of GTAP-BIO simulations wherein the calibrated crop yield responses are modified. In particular, they are increased such that they also contribute to 40% of the ex ante production effects. These new calibrated crop yield elasticities lead to much more credible substitution elasticities that govern the optimal combination of inputs and factors. The new substitution elasticities fit better with available econometric results. Above all, the crop yield effects matter nearly as much as in the FAPRI analysis. The introduction of realistic crop yield elasticities, relative to production elasticities, leads to a dramatic decline in the land use changes (and a similar dramatic increase in GHG saving) induced by the biofuel production.

II. On the Calibration of Production, Land, and Yield Responses in the Gtap-Bio and Fapri Models

The GTAP-BIO model is a variant of the static Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP) model widely used for the global economic analysis of trade, poverty, energy, and environmental issues. Several improvements to the underlying database (such as the introduction of the different feedstocks or biofuel by-products) and the modeling of behavioral responses (such as the specification of multiproduct activities at the processing stage or the calibration of elasticities) have been progressively implemented to perform relevant biofuel policy analysis (the numerous improvements are reviewed by Golub and Hertel [2012]).

The Specification of Agricultural Supplies

The agricultural supply side is fully described by Keeney and Hertel (2009). This paper recalls, below, the most important assumptions. There exists a representative producer in each agricultural sector and region. These mono-product farmers maximize their profits subject to technical, market (prices), and political (subsidies/taxes) constraints. The agricultural supply response to output price shocks and its decomposition between yield and land responses are calibrated by two types of structural parameters: the substitution elasticities between inputs, and the elasticities of transformation governing the mobility of inputs between sectors. The latter elasticities determine the supply elasticities of these inputs to each agricultural sector.

For the substitution elasticities, I first note that in the GTAP-BIO model five types of inputs are distinguished in each agricultural production technology: land, labor, capital, energy products, and other inputs. It is theoretically possible to specify 10 free substitution elasticities in each agricultural technology; in practice, only 2 substitution elasticities are specified, due to the imposed separability assumptions. More precisely, each agricultural technology is specified with a nested CES production structure. At the lowest level of the production structure, the substitution between the capital and energy products is specified with a first CES function. At the intermediate level, a second CES function defines the substitution among land, labor, and an aggregate comprising capital and energy products. Finally, at the upper level of the production structure, a third CES function defines the substitution between the value-added composite and the other inputs. It is furthermore assumed that the second and third CES functions share the same elasticity of substitution.

The supply elasticities of inputs to each agricultural sector (captured by the elasticities of transformation) differ according to the horizon considered for the analysis. Most analyses consider a long-run horizon that is relevant when computing the net GHG emissions of biofuels (the 30-year period of amortization). All inputs are assumed to be perfectly elastic in the long run. The only exception is land, where total land is assumed to be fixed. Its allocation among the different crop sectors, pasture, forest, and other uses is governed by a nested constant elasticity of transformation (CET) structure. In particular, a first CET allocates cropland to each crop sector.

In mathematical terms, these different assumptions lead to the following system of land and production responses to an output price shock in a given agricultural sector:

Embedded Image [1]Embedded Image [2]Embedded Image [3]

where q, l, pq, and pl are the percentage changes of production, land use, output price, and land rental price; σ and Embedded Image are the substitution and land supply elasticities, respectively; and sl is the initial share of land in production cost. Equation [1] is the derived demand of land, equation [2] is the zero profit condition that implicitly determines the optimal production levels, and equation [3] is the land supply condition. These equations are adapted from Keeney and Hertel (2009) to account for the constant Allen Uzawa elasticity of substitution across pairs of inputs.

From these three equations, we can compute the ex ante elasticities of output, land and yields with respect to the output price:

Embedded Image [4]Embedded Image [5]Embedded Image [6]
TABLE 1

Elasticities of Substitution between Inputs (σ) and Ex Ante Elasticities of Production Embedded Image, Land Embedded Image, and Yields Embedded Image with Respect to the Corn Price in the GTAP-BIO Framework

The output elasticity (equation [4]) is thus composed of two terms, the land elasticity (equation [5]) and the yield elasticity (equation [6]). It appears that the last equation depends only on the substitution elasticity. This substitution elasticity is calibrated in the GTAP-BIO to target a given yield elasticity. Above all, these equations make clear that the calibration of yield elasticity is made independently of the calibration of the output elasticity. If the elasticity of land supply or the share of land in production cost is low, then the land response is high (equation [5]). As a result, a high output elasticity is obtained even if the yield elasticity is low, which implies that ex ante an output price increase will lead mostly to land use changes and a modest yield effect.

The Calibration Results

Table 1 reports these ex ante elasticities for major countries producing corn using initial land shares from the GTAP-BIO database and an elasticity of 0.5 for the CET function allocating cropland. This table also provides the resulting substitution elasticities for later discussion. The world production elasticity is a production-weighted sum of regional production elasticities in order to take into account the different regional corn prices. Finally, we compute the contribution of yield elasticities in the output elasticities. This table is divided into two parts. The first part provides the results when the targeted yield elasticity equals 0.2; the second part provides the same results when the target yield elasticity equals 0.4. These two figures are those retained in the final CARB analysis.

The results show that in all countries, the initial yield elasticity is much lower than the output elasticity. For instance, when the targeted yield is 0.2, the initial U.S. production elasticity is 2.67. Hence, the ex ante yield effects represent only 7.5% of the production effects. At the world level, the initial yield elasticity is slightly larger than the targeted elasticity (0.32 compared to 0.2) due to an aggregation effect (initial yields differ greatly across regions). However, the fact remains that the initial yield elasticity is small compared with the output elasticity by representing only 8.1%.

When the targeted yield elasticity increases to 0.4, we find, as expected, larger substitution elasticities and output elasticities (see equations [6] and [4]). All output elasticities increase by 0.2, while the land elasticities remain constant. At the world level, the yield elasticity now represents 12.5% of the output elasticity.

However, the available information suggests that the introduction of yield effects is ex ante much more consequent with the FAPRI model. Table 2 also reports the output, land, and yield elasticities specified in this model. In its standard version, the yield elasticities are assumed to be zero. They are positive in the variant described by Dumortier et al. (2011). Land elasticities are taken from the FAPRI website2 for all countries excluding the United States, where a more sophisticated modeling of farm supply is specified and prevents direct computation. The world aggregate reported in Table 2 excludes the U.S. figures. The world aggregate is a weighted sum using production and acreage observed in 2009.

The yield elasticity for corn introduced in the FAPRI model is thus lower than in the CARB analysis using the GTAP-BIO model (approximately 0.12 compared with a range between 0.2 and 0.4). However, the contributions of yield responses to output responses are much higher. For instance, they are 65.2% for Europe and 45.8% for China. By comparison, these contributions are lower than 12% with the GTAP-BIO framework. At the world level, the contribution of yield in output response is 38.0% with the FAPRI model compared to, at most, 12.5% with the GTAP-BIO model. Accordingly, one may already understand why the impacts of crop yield effects on the land use changes and the net GHG emissions induced by biofuels are different across the two frameworks.

TABLE 2

Ex Ante Elasticities of Production Embedded Image, Land Embedded Image, and Yields Embedded Image with Respect to the Corn Price in the FAPRI Framework

The foregoing analysis focuses on the ex ante effects of corn prices on yield and land use change effects. It should be added that the final price effects are endogenous in both models and also depend on the demand responses. The ex ante price and land change effects following a biofuel demand shock (denoted below by ΔD) are given by

Embedded Image [7]Embedded Image [8]

where Embedded Image is the own price demand elasticity.

These expressions are identical to those of Hertel (2011) and make clear that the ratio of the yield elasticity to the land elasticity matters more than the absolute value of the yield elasticity. With larger crop yield responses, the output responses are increased considerably with the FAPRI model and more marginally with the GTAP-BIO model. This means that the resulting price effects (and food displacement effects) may become less significant in the former compared with the latter. Hence, the final impacts of the crop yield calibration on these GHG results are much more complex than the foregoing ex ante analysis focusing on the corn supply side only would suggest. Additional complexities come from the fact that in the GTAP-BIO model, the output, land, and yield elasticities are not constant but rather evolve with, for example, input cost shares (see equations [4] to [6]). Moreover, there are cross product effects (from other arable crop markets), size effects (shocks do not always imply small price effects), and regional effects (for instance, the corn price may change in different proportions in different countries due to trade instruments). For this reason, I now turn to simulations using the GTAP-BIO model with a different calibration of crop yield elasticities.

TABLE 3

Elasticities of Substitution between Inputs (σ) and Ex Ante Elasticities of Production Embedded Image, Land Embedded Image, and Yields Embedded Image with Respect to the Coarse Grain Price in the GTAP-BIO Framework

III. Impacts of Alternative Calibrations of Crop Yield Responses With The Gtap-Bio Model

This section reports the main results obtained with the GTAP-BIO model from a 13.25 billion gallon increase of the U.S. production of corn ethanol from 1.75 to 15 billion gallons, a volume authorized by the Energy Independence and Security Act of 2007. This is the experiment analyzed by the CARB.

Below, first I justify the alternative calibrations of crop yield elasticities. Then, I analyze the main results. Finally, I perform a sensitivity analysis of the horizon considered in the analysis (and, hence, the values of the production elasticities).

The Alternative Calibrations

I first analyze the biofuel shock with the standard parameters of the GTAP-BIO model (particularly regarding the mobility of factors between sectors). The targeted yield elasticity is assumed to be 0.2. This first version allows understanding of the ex post contribution of crop yield responses in production responses for different countries. I then explore two alternative calibrations of the crop yield responses while maintaining ex ante land effects. That is, I proceed as in the CARB analysis and adopt a long-run horizon in the benchmark.

To make the results as comparable as possible to the FAPRI results, I consider in the first alternative no ex ante crop yield responses.3 The resulting ex ante elasticities are provided in the first part of Table 3. In the second alternative, I consider larger ex ante crop yield responses. I emphasize, as do many other authors, that the choice of precise yield elasticities is delicate. All biofuel analyses recognize that there is limited knowledge on the extent of crop yield and production elasticities with respect to output prices. Keeney and Hertel (2009) and the expert work group on elasticities requested by the CARB (Babcock, Gurgel, and Stowers 2010) devote significant efforts to gathering econometric evidence on the yield elasticities. Unfortunately, most econometric papers focus only on the yield elasticities without simultaneously considering the production (and land) elasticities. The exception is the recent analysis by Huang and Khanna (2010), which develops a reduced form econometric analysis. These authors estimate crop yield elasticities of 0.06, 0.15, and 0.43 for soybeans, corn, and wheat, respectively. They also estimate crop land elasticities that acknowledge cross price effects. Thus, it is impossible to consistently compute the production elasticities using their reduced form approach. Let us ignore the cross price elasticities on land use estimated by these authors, so that the following computed production elasticities overestimate the true ones. The resulting production elasticities are 0.55, 0.66, and 0.50 for soybeans, corn, and wheat, respectively. Accordingly, the contribution of crop yield elasticities in production elasticities is certainly greater than 11%, 23%, and 86% for soybeans, corn, and wheat, respectively. The percentage for corn is much higher than the ex ante percentage assumed in the GTAP-BIO model for U.S. corn (13.9% when the target yield elasticity is 0.4).

This discussion demonstrates the issue of choosing a particular value for crop yield elasticities independently of the production elasticities. The calibration procedure ensures that the value of one elasticity is fulfilled, but without controlling for the others. In this paper, I do not want to claim to choose the true values for all elasticities. Rather, I want to make the sensitivity analysis of crop yields from the GTAP-BIO model comparable to that of the FAPRI model. Accordingly, I define the value of the corn yield elasticity such that its ex ante contribution to the production response equals the FAPRI one defined at the world level (38%). The resulting value is rounded to 2. The second part of Table 3 reports the corresponding ex ante elasticities. Applying the same corn yield elasticity to all countries, we find that the ex ante shares of yield effects in production effects become closer to the FAPRI shares, particularly for China. These shares remain lower for Europe and greater for Brazil.

Above all, this much higher calibrated yield elasticity implies much higher substitution elasticities between inputs (approximately 0.4, depending on the country). These figures appear more consistent with available econometric estimates than the initial GTAP-BIO implied values (all lower than 0.1). For instance, Abler (2001) conducts an extensive literature review of these elasticities for the United States, Canada, and Mexico. Considering all studies, he finds that for the U.S. the average elasticity of substitution between land and other farmer-owned inputs equals 0.3 and that the average elasticity of substitution between land and purchased inputs equals 0.5. Salhofer (2001) performs a similar review for European countries. He finds that the average elasticity of substitution between land and other primary factors lies between 0.1 and 0.3 and that the average elasticity of substitution between land and other inputs lies between 1.6 and 2.7.

In other words, here the absolute value of the crop yield elasticity is certainly high compared with the available econometric estimates. However, this value is more credible when considered relative to the production elasticities and when compared with available econometric evidence on substitution elasticities.

Results

This discussion first focuses on the main results for corn markets obtained from the three calibrations of yield elasticities. Let us begin with the initial calibration (ex ante yield elasticity of 0.2) retained in the CARB analysis (the middle part of Table 4). Unsurprisingly, the results show an increase in U.S. corn production of 16.38%. It appears that this production increase is obtained by a greater increase of the corn harvested area (by 17.10%).4 Hence, with the initial calibration there is a slight decrease of U.S. corn yield. Impacts on other countries are quite modest compared with the United States. The production impacts amount to 2.09% in Brazil and only 0.54% in Europe. This is explained by the modest price transmission implied by the so-called Armington modeling of trade flows.5 At the world level, there is an increase of production by 4.32% and an increase of harvested area by 2.78%. Corn yield at the world level thus increases by 1.54%, contributing to 36% of the production increase. This result is mainly explained by an aggregation effect: the corn production increases most in the United States, where the initial yield is greater than in other countries. In all countries and at the world level, the ex post elasticities are quite different from the ex ante elasticities. For instance, the ex post U.S. production elasticity is lower than one (precisely 16.38/ 17.08), while its ex ante level is 2.67. Nevertheless, it is interesting to note that the ex post world yield elasticity (0.34) is close to its calibrated value (0.32). Having explained the major effects of the biofuel shock for a given calibration, I can now examine the impact of modifying the calibration of crop yield elasticities.

TABLE 4

Impacts on the Coarse Grain Markets of the Biofuel Shock According to Three Calibrations of Yield Elasticities Embedded Image (in Percentage with Respect to the 2001 GTAP-BIO Database)

I first consider the results when the ex ante yield elasticity is zero (first part of Table 4). As expected, there are now lower yield effects. For instance, the U.S. corn yield decreases by 3.57 compared with a decrease of 0.72 with the previous calibration. By contrast, the land use changes are greater: the U.S. harvested area increases by 18.33% (compared with 17.10%). We also find greater price effects because the corn production becomes less price sensitive. For the same biofuel demand shock, the production values increase less, and thus other demands (for feed and food) adjust more. Again, the production effects are quite modest in other countries due to the imperfect price transmission. Corn yields increase only in China. At the world level, we find lower yield effects and greater land use changes: the world corn harvested area increases by 3.21% compared with 2.78% with the previous calibration.

Finally, let us consider the third calibration. The direction of results is perfectly symmetrical. As expected, the production and yield effects are now greater, while the land use and price effects are lower. At the world level, there is an increase of corn harvested area amounting to 1.40%, which represents 44% of the impact obtained when the ex ante crop yield effects are null. This does not imply that the total land use changes and GHG emissions also decrease by the same percentage; the impacts on other arable crop markets must also be taken into account. Table 5 provides the main results for the other grain, oilseed, and sugar crop markets at the world level.

As expected, we find that the positive price impacts on these other arable crops decrease with the price responsiveness of crop yields. We also find that the ex post yield effects tend to increase when the ex ante yield elasticities increase. The exception is for the other grains market (the world yield increases by only 0.79 with the third calibration) because the own price effect vanishes. Finally, we find that the land use tends to decrease when the ex ante yield elasticities increase. This is particularly the case for oilseeds. When the ex ante yield elasticity is zero, the world oilseed harvested area increases by 0.63%. This results mainly from a reduction in the U.S. oilseed production compensated for by increases in countries such as Canada, the European Union, and Sub-Saharan Africa countries with initially lower yields. In contrast, when the ex ante yield elasticity is 2, then the world oilseed harvested area decreases by 0.49%. We thus find, as did Golub and Hertel (2012), that these crop market effects are also dramatic.

The final impacts in terms of cropland converted, reduction of forest and pasture land, and the land use change carbon intensity (as computed by the CARB) are reported in Table 6. We find that the increase of cropland is much reduced when the ex ante yield elasticity increases in relative terms, as in the FAPRI analysis: from 8.81 million ha when the ex ante crop elasticity is zero to 1.17 million ha when it is 2. The reduction of forest land and pasture land due to the biofuel shock are both significantly altered. Finally, we find that the land use change carbon intensity is dramatically reduced from 68.6 to 10.8 gCO2eq/MJ. Although not the same as the FAPRI results, they are much closer to them. The calibration of yield elasticities relative to production elasticities thus matters greatly: it crucially determines the potential efficiency of the biofuel policy in mitigating carbon emissions.

Sensitivity Analysis to the Length of Run

Thus far, I have considered a long-run horizon where all primary factors of production are fully mobile across sectors. The only exception was land. This implies quite large production and land elasticities. In the preceding analysis, I increase the crop yield elasticities without changing these land elasticities and factor mobilities. To check the robustness of the previous results and to adopt production elasticities that are more consistent with available econometric evidence, I now assume, like Keeney and Hertel (2009), that labor and capital are not perfectly mobile across sectors, and adopt a unitary elasticity of mobility.

The issue in this case is that there is no longer a direct correspondence between the substitution elasticity and the crop yield elasticity. This is because an output price increase translates into an increase in the land (rental) price and an increase in the labor/capital (rental) prices as well. To illustrate, let us temporarily assume that only the labor supply is imperfectly elastic. In this case, the ex ante elasticities of output, land, and yields with respect to the output price are given by

Embedded Image [9]Embedded Image [10]Embedded Image [11]

where the subscript n stands for labor. Equation [11] makes clear that the ex ante yield elasticity depends on the relative supply elasticities of land and labor. It is also the same ratio of factor supply elasticities that now appears in the ex ante land elasticities (equation [10]): if the labor supply is imperfectly elastic, then the ex ante land (and production) elasticity is lower than it was previously.

In this sensitivity analysis, I vary the substitution elasticities, picking those adopted previously and justified by econometric evidence for the higher elasticities. Table 7 reports the ex ante production, land, and yield elasticities for corn at the world level. This table also reports the ex post impacts of the biofuel shock on the corn price and the land use change carbon intensity.

By definition, the ex ante production and land elasticities are now lower. For instance, when no substitution is allowed between land and other inputs, the world ex ante production elasticity for corn amounts to 1.67 (compared with 3.76). When the substitution elasticity is taken from the previous third calibration, the world production elasticity amounts to 2.12 (compared with 5.76 previously). In this case, the world ex ante yield elasticity amounts to 0.74 and thus represents 35% of the production elasticities. This value remains quite close to the share computed from the FAPRI analysis.

TABLE 5

World Impacts on Other Arable Crop Markets of the Biofuel Shock According to Three Calibrations of Yield Elasticities Embedded Image (in Percentage with Respect to the 2001 GTAP-BIO Database)

The simulation results show, as expected, greater price impacts than those obtained so far. The simple reason for this result is that the supply side of the corn market is less price-responsive. More importantly, the carbon intensity is also provided. We again find a very significant impact of allowing ex ante crop yield effects: the level of reduction is more in line with the FAPRI results.

IV. Concluding Comments

The land use changes and carbon intensity implied by biofuel production are difficult empirical issues that have motivated much research in recent years. Available analyses show that the assumptions on the responsiveness of crop yields to prices matter greatly in these computations. However, the extent of these impacts differs significantly across the leading modeling frameworks. The analysis conducted with the FAPRI model on U.S. corn ethanol estimates that the introduction of moderate crop yield elasticities (lower than 0.2) implies a reduction of the carbon intensity by 93 gCO2eq/MJ. By contrast, the analysis conducted with the GTAP-BIO model estimates that a similar moderate increase of crop yield elasticities (from 0.2 to 0.4) implies a reduction of the carbon intensity of corn ethanol by 10 gCO2eq/MJ only. The policy implications of these results are quite different: Hertel et al. (2010) doubt the potential contribution of the biofuel policy to mitigating global warming, while Dumortier et al. (2011) are more positive if future yield improvements are attainable.

TABLE 6

World Impacts of the Biofuel Shock on the Land Use Changes and Carbon Intensity According to Three Calibrations of Yield Elasticities Embedded Image

TABLE 7

Sensitivity of Biofuel Impacts to the Substitution Elasticities σ in the Medium Run

In this paper, I reveal that these results of sensitivity to crop yield elasticity are not comparable because the ex ante land and production elasticities assumed in these two models are not comparable. However, when the shares of crop yield elasticities in production elasticities are made comparable, there is a much more similar dramatic reduction of land use changes and carbon intensity. The policy implication is that the biofuel policy may appear more efficient than previously recognized if one additionally assumes that the price-induced yield improvements observed in the past are still possible in the future. Without fully solving the land use change problem, yield responses may seriously water down this controversial issue. But the fundamental problem remains how to measure the relative longterm efficiency of the biofuel policy compared to other policy measures.

The contribution of this paper is also methodological: the analysis reveals that the focus on the absolute value of the yield elasticity can be misleading. Rather, it is more important to ensure the consistency of the different elasticities calibrated in the agroeconomic models. From this perspective, I recommend the econometric estimation of economic systems where the different economic mechanisms (e.g., land use, fertilizer application, pest management, labor/capital allocation) are specified. This certainly raises new challenges due to the limited data available to perform such estimations (for an illustration of the identification of variable inputs applied by crops, see Carpentier and Letort [2012]). However, in light of the many recent debates surrounding the evolution of the world agricultural supply, these data-gathering costs are likely to be lower than the expected future benefits.

Acknowledgments

The author would like to thank the two referees and the editor for their constructive comments. All remaining errors are the sole responsibility of the author

Footnotes

  • The author is director of research, UMR SMART Agrocampus Ouest INRA, Rennes, France.

  • 1 In the same vein, Golub and Hertel (2012) report that when the price elasticity of crop yields increases from 0.1 to 0.25, then the world's additional cropland decreases by 27%. Analyses on soy biodiesel performed by the CARB (2010) lead to similar effects: when the output price elasticity of crop yields increases from 0.2 to 0.4, the land use change carbon intensity decreases from 93 to 73 gCO2eq/ MJ (hence, a 22% decrease).

  • 2 See www.fapri.org.

  • 3 I fix the target elasticity at 0.01 and not 0 because the model fails to run in this case.

  • 4 Table 4 provides the harvested areas rather than the so-called effective areas that are also modeled with the GTAP-BIO model (see Golub and Hertel [2012] for the distinction). This choice was made because the FAPRI analysis focuses on these harvested areas. In fact, yields slightly increase on initial corn acreages (by 3% in the United States), but yields are lower on marginal lands devoted to corn production.

  • 5 I modified the Armington value forthe corn and, like Golub and Hertel 2012, find that the world effects are only marginally affected.

References